Email or username:

Password:

Forgot your password?
Top-level
Carl T. Bergstrom

The basic issue at hand is high-risk, high-return science. There is widespread sentiment, and even some scattered empirical evidence, that scientific research within academia is too cautious and that higher-risk, higher-return research would yield more progress more quickly.

High-risk, high return research.

(wheel of fortune spinning)
10 comments
Carl T. Bergstrom

If you ask people why we don't see more high-risk science, you get different answers. Researchers tell you that granting agencies won't fund it. Funders tell you that researchers won't propose it.

Two ravens squabbling in the sand.
Carl T. Bergstrom

A couple of years ago, we published a PNAS paper that tackles the researchers' side of the story, explaining why grant review panels may be unlikely to fund risky studies.

pnas.org/doi/10.1073/pnas.2111

The present paper addresses the funding agencies' side, and looks at why researchers may be reluctant to take on high-risk projects even if they are funded.

Carl T. Bergstrom

To get at this, we have think about the incentives that academic researchers face.

Because it's very difficult to monitor the effort that researchers put in, academic scientists are rewarded almost exclusively for their research output.

Rewards come in the form of jobs, promotions, salary, and prestige, for example. We'll refer to these all as wages.

Female Barrow's goldeneye on still water.
Carl T. Bergstrom

We note that particularly where job security and salary are concerned, scientists are risk-averse in wages.

Belted kingfisher on a post
Carl T. Bergstrom

When investing in risky research, funding agencies can hedge their bets across a portfolio of large-scale high-risk projects. Individual scientists can't typically do this.

Brant geese flying.
Carl T. Bergstrom

Researchers might be willing to take on risky projects if they could be insured against that risk, with wages that didn't depend on the vicissitudes of scientific fortune.

But you can't completely ensure against the failure to get results, because bad luck is indistinguishable from loafing and you need to somehow incentivize effort.

Barn swallow on a rope
Carl T. Bergstrom

Thus the scientific enterprise is caught in a bind. Measures necessary to incentive effort necessarily dissuade researchers from taking enough risks.

Flamingo neck in a figure 8
Carl T. Bergstrom

A social planner might induce effort and risk by paying large bonuses for major results.

But given any budget to allocate among researchers, this is inefficient from the researchers' perspective because risk aversion means that to increase the utility of a high earner even modestly, you have to take a lot of wages away from low earners at high utility cost.

Two ravens, one flying inverted below the other.
Carl T. Bergstrom

But here's the thing: science has no external social planner.

Scientists themselves determine what results are considered worthwhile, and how worthwhile. They decide who is hired, promoted, given wages, is awarded prizes, and garners esteem. In other words, they set their own wages, of course subject to a budget constraint.

Interior of Stanford Chapel, wide angel view.
Carl T. Bergstrom replied to Carl T. Bergstrom

What we prove in this paper is that (in a simple model of the scientific enterprise), when left to their own devices scientists will choose for themselves a wage scheme that results in below-optimal risk-taking.

This is an inevitable consequence of the unobservability of effort and risk, coupled with the lack of an external social planner.

In other words, the rewards the science collective offers are not sufficient to motivating socially optimal levels of scientific risk.

Bees feeding on purple allium flowers.
Go Up